Episode #15 – Imports, Exports, and Exchange Rates

 

Crash Course came out in Episode 15 to talk about International Trade.  Maybe this is a reaction to some political candidates talking about the Chinese trade deficit.  Regardless of the motive, this episode was economically sound in content, while the tone may not have been along the same lines.

This Episode’s Major Principle

tv

Imagine that I have a choice of buying an American made TV or a TV made in Malaysia.  Because of lower labor costs in Malaysia the imported TV cost $200 less than the American made one. So I buy the imported TV. That may cost jobs at a TV factory in the US but I saved $200 by buying the imported TV.    

And what am I gonna do with those $200? I’m gonna spend them on something I couldn’t have afforded if I bought the US TV. Like maybe taking my family out to a baseball game or to a restaurant. That creates jobs in those industries that wouldn’t have existed if I’d bought the more expensive TV.

Remember Episode 2, on comparative advantage?  Crash Course has already explained that international trade between two countries helps both countries, even if one is poorer or less productive.

More importantly, international trade doesn’t only help the businesses who are trading, but it helps consumers who are able to save more with each purchase.  That money saved can either go to spending on other goods (creating jobs in those areas) or in the bank (which gets lent out to growing businesses).

But in the same breath of mentioning how international trade helps everyone involved (including consumers), Crash Course goes a little off the rails:

Capture

Economic Theory suggests that international trade shuffles jobs from one sector of the economy to another, like from the TV factory to the restaurant.  But the quality of these jobs can be markedly different.  The guy assembling TVs at the US factory was probably making a lot more at his manufacturing job before he got reshuffled to the burrito assembly line at Chipotle.

As technology improves and consumer demands shift, employees will have to move from certain sectors of the economy to others.  But Crash Course does some injustice to the former factory employee.  Why would this employee get a job at Chipotle?  Because assembling a burrito is like assembling a TV?

If domestic manufacturing shrinks, another sector is likely to grow.  And as the factory employee takes a new job somewhere else, his skills and work product will likely determine his pay.

Trade does not just shuffle jobs from one sector to another; it moves jobs from less productive areas of the economy to more productive areas of the economy.  If Malaysia is better at producing TVs for a cheaper price (assuming both countries’ TVs are the same in quality), then it’s better to have American employees working in areas that can compete internationally, instead of making TVs that will be no one will buy because it’s too expensive.

What Crash Course did not explain is what happens when protectionist policies prevent international trade (this is sometimes referred to as Mercantilism).  For example, let’s say the US government imposes taxes and fees that make the price of Malaysian TVs higher than US TVs.  It will keep that factory employee at the manufacturing plant, but everyone else in the economy will be worse off, as they have to pay more of their paycheck for their TV.

NAFTA

nafta

NAFTA is a polarizing political issue, and depending on which camp you’re most affiliated with, you will regard the agreement as either a huge success and a catastrophic failure.  For example, Democrat Party loyalists or Bill Clinton supporters will call it success, since it happened under his presidency.  Labor Unions hate it, since it removed trade barriers that kept some American producers afloat (like the TV example explained above).  Libertarians and free marketeers are a mix about it, for reasons I will explain.

Like the TPP agreement currently in the works, NAFTA was heavily influenced by corporate interests, and parts of the agreement were tailored specifically to benefit these companies.  NAFTA was a free market international agreement, but not for all goods across the board, just the ones outlined in the legislation.  NAFTA was a move toward freer markets, but it was orchestrated in a way that reeked of cronyism.

Thus, politicians and pundits alike had to choose sides:  Do I support the Democratic Party more than I support Labor Unions?  Do I support free markets more than I oppose crony legislation?

Crash Course comes down in favor of NAFTA, as they should if they were looking purely at economic benefits:

So despite the fact that some workers and industries were clearly hurt, economists would tell us NAFTA has had a net positive impact on all three countries.

Are Trade Deficits Bad?

trade

Crash Course doesn’t clearly explain how they stand on trade deficits, but you can infer from the end of video that although they agree they make everyone better off, they sympathize (possibly more so) with those who are negatively affected by international trade:

In purely economic terms trade deficits and surpluses are the result of people and nations seeking their own self-interests. But while everyone is acting in the self-interested way, international trade doesn’t always meet our individual interests. What might be good for the wider global economy, might be really bad for me or my hometown. But in the aggregate, trade does improve the global standard of living. It’s just sometimes hard to see up close.

As I mentioned before, the alternative to international trade makes everyone worse off.  While it’s easier to witness the negative effects of international trade (since people are laid off), it would be much worse if domestic businesses were protected from international competition.  Resources would be wasted, prices would be higher, and the living standards of everyone (rich and poor alike) would be worse.

As a final note, Crash Course never responds to people who say that trade deficits “ship jobs overseas”.  An excerpt from this article does an excellent job at illustrating why this does not happen:

japan

If say Toyota sells a Japanese-manufactured car in the United States, then they have two options as to what they shall do with the money: either buy American goods and services, in case which the trade deficit does not increase, or they can buy American assets which will increase the pool of funding for investments in America, or they can try to exchange the dollars earned into yen, which someone will have to sell to them and then use it for one of Toyota’s two first options.

Trade deficits are offset by capital surpluses, which in this case is Toyota having to spend US dollars somewhere in the American economy.  These dollars, in addition to the dollars saved by Americans who buy a cheaper Toyota instead of a more expensive Ford car, contribute to the economy and create growth (and jobs) in other areas.

Crash Course Episode #9, Deficits and Debt, Part 1

In this week’s episode of Crash Course Economics, the hosts talk about deficits and debt.  This episode might have better scheduled if it were before the videos on Keynesian Macroeconomic Policy, where they talked about deficits and debt, only to define the terms later.

Debt and Spending

Crash Course opens the episode by defining the terms debt and deficit, and explaining how the United States has the largest debt of any country, but the US debt as a percentage of GDP is not as high as a few other countries whose economies are doing fine, namely Japan.  However, the major concern isn’t the current size of the debt, but the growing deficit.

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 12.05.45 PM

Most economists are not worried about the borrowing that the US has done already, because they are too worries about the borrowing they’re going to do.

This is true, and as shown in the graph above, the US deficit is scheduled to increase through in future decades as government spending increases.

In the “too much spending vs. not enough revenue” argument, Crash Course shows that revenue (i.e. taxes, fees, tariffs, etc.) is set to increase (as a percentage of GDP) in the coming decades, so this is “not the problem”.  While this is a subjective political argument (socialists and progressives might say that taxes are not high enough), we’ll assume that what she meant was that the increasing deficit is caused by increasing government spending, not decreasing revenue.

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 3.27.13 PM

To de-politicize the spending issue, our co-host Adriene gives her explanation of which side is right when it comes to the question of “Where is there too much spending?”:

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 3.35.00 PM

Let’s look at where the government actually spends its money.  Conservatives might complain “It’s obvious!  Handouts!”  Liberals will say “It’s obvious!  Defense!” Well, they’re both wrong.  So who’s the biggest recipient of federal dollars?

Grandma and Grandpa.  The government spends about a quarter of the budget on Social Security, and another quarter on healthcare programs.  A lot of that goes to retired people on Medicare.  They deserve it!  They worked hard.  And those are the programs that are expected to grow as baby boomers retire and live longer.  Defense and other discretionary programs are actually projected to shrink slightly as a percentage of GDP.

First, let’s ignore the out-of-place and opinionated commentary of “they deserve it!  They worked hard.”

Second, while retirement spending is scheduled to increase significantly, so is defense.

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 3.42.46 PM

The graph above shows the nominal costs of the Department of Defense.  Until about 2022, there is an increase in spending.  After that, it will stay at about 600 billion per year.

However, Adriene is right that Defense will shrink as a percentage of GDP, as you can see in the graph above.  So if we’re looking at the cause of the increase in the deficit, as opposed to the already large deficit/debt or spending in general, she is correct.

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 3.48.59 PM

Also, if tax-funded healthcare for the elderly is one of the leading causes of the increasing deficit, are conservatives actually wrong when they complain about “handouts”?  I understand that Crash Course tries to remain politically neutral, but if the argument is between handouts vs. defense being the cause of a rising deficit, and you explain that Medicare is a primary cause, conservatives (in this case) are not wrong.

Also, in the liberals vs. conservatives argument, rarely have I heard the argument phrased within the context of defecit as percentage of GDP.  Liberals are usually arguing that there is and has been too much defense spending generally, and conservatives argue against handouts being such a large part of the budget generally.

Debt and Borrowing

Our co-host Mr. Clifford explains how the US finances its debt:

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 4.04.57 PM

First, to borrow, you need lenders, people who have decided to save money and loan it out, rather than spend it on something else.  But there is a finite amount of money that savers can lend, and most of that savings is borrowed by the private sector, which is consumer that take out car loans and businesses that pay for things like factories and computers.

When the government runs a budget deficit, it borrows from that same pool of savings.  And if the government continues to borrow, many economists worry that there will be fewer loans available for businesses, and that will hurt the long-run growth of the economy.

This is a huge misrepresentation of how government fuels its debt.  Here is a graph that accurately shows who hold the government debt:

Screen shot 2015-10-05 at 4.16.47 PM

As you can see, domestic private investors, like what Mr. Clifford was talking about, account for less than 15% of government debt.  The largest portion (34%) comes from international investors, which could be foreign governments or foreign citizens who are lending money to the US government and hoping to be paid back when the bond matures.

Federal Accounts accounts for 28%.  This is where the government essentially borrows money from itself.  Since different departments have different budgets, and some don’t necessarily need to spend it this year (for example, the budget that holds the Social Security deposits you’ve contributing to and hoping to get back eventually), other departments can borrow from those accounts and promise to pay it back later.

The Federal Reserve accounts for 14% of the debt.  This is when the government creates money with a push of a button and buys treasury bonds (which is what you get when you loan money to the government).  When the loans matures, the money is then just put into the treasury.

This is a big misrepresentation by Crash Course, and I was very surprised that they described US debt holders as only domestic lenders.  How did this script get through production without someone saying “maybe we should say that this is only about 15% of debt, and there are many other ways the US finances its debt?”

We’ll pick back up with the rest of the video in Part 2.  Stay tuned to see what Crash Course says about interest rates, and scenarios when spending might not get out of control.

 

Like what I wrote? Hate it?  Drop some feedback in the comments.  Also sign up for the Newsletter.